This essay received 39/45 which is a low level 5. To have received more marks I would have needed to sustain my overall argument and integrate the judgements made at the end earlier on in the essay.
To what extent did perestroika and glasnost succeed in
reforming the political and economic systems of the USSR?
In 1985 Mikhail Gorbachev came
to power to lead a Soviet Union approaching collapse. He proposed two different
strands of reform, the first perestroika, meaning restructuring, and to
accompany this, glasnost, meaning openness. Through perestroika, Gorbachev
hoped to reform the structures of both the bureaucratic, command and stagnating
economic system, and the undemocratic, conservative political system of the USSR,
while glasnost was intended to encourage a greater openness across the
political and social spectrum. However, it is debatable as to whether these
political and economic systems were reformed to the extent they possibly could have
been, or whether this extent had been compromised by Gorbachev’s inconsistent
and incoherent reform. Progress was limited due to the contradictory nature of
perestroika, as well as Glasnost being undermined by the scepticism of media
freedoms. Therefore, perestroika and glasnost had little success in reforming
the systems of the USSR.
Gorbachev introduced economic
perestroika as the introduction of market forces within the confines of the
command economy that already existed, demonstrating that Gorbachev never
intended to remove the existing command system, but rather streamline it to
address the economic crisis that had resulted from the “Era of Stagnation” under
Brezhnev. This already indicates that the extent of economic reform perestroika
was expected to achieve was to be limited to continuing Stalinist central
planning. In perestroika’s first phase of acceleration, the economic system was
operating within a traditional framework because rather than use radical change
to assist the economy, Gorbachev believed in “accelerated growth” achieved via
tinkering. The 12th Five Year Plan was set with considerably higher
targets, continuing the Stalinist system of quantity being emphasised over
quality, and as a result the economy was denied breathing space to rejuvenate. This
rejuvenation was hoped to be achieved with the introduction of new production
methods that would mean targets were met, but the opposite occurred. Instead,
workers would revert back to lying about targets instead of trying to meet
them, or simply refuse to overtly comply because they were expected to work
harder for the same pay. The deficiencies of low productivity, corruption and
bureaucracy remained because radical change wasn’t being attempted, and by this
time the Stalinist system could was no longer applicable to the economic crisis
facing the USSR. Despite the target of doubling national income by 2000, by
April 1987 this had declined. Therefore in its early stages, perestroika
neither achieved, nor aimed to achieve radical reform of the obsolete command
economy, but rather stick to the traditional framework, but accelerate it.
Reform was only attempted during
acceleration through new innovations, including the Law on Individual Labour
Activity of November 1986, which allowed some
private enterprise, particularly in service sectors. Private enterprise had
always been antagonised and controlled in the Soviet system, therefore to have
produced reform that sought to encourage it may lead to the conclusion of
Laver, that Gorbachev provided “a style of leadership not seen before in the
USSR”. However, this was limited to the service sectors, not to mention the
actuality proved otherwise, as enterprise was stifled with the long-existing
“bureaucratic obstructionism” of conservative ministries, and while on paper,
the law hoped to end the stigma surrounding private enterprise, the reality was
that profit motive was still deemed as “anti-social”, or rather anti-socialist,
and was “unearned income”. Subsequently, the economy continued to decline
because no restructuring had occurred, consequently the economy was not
reinvigorated, and Gorbachev’s credibility as a reformer dwindled, making it
even harder for him to bring about radical reform in the next phase of
perestroika. Therefore even if workers had wanted to innovate to achieve the
targets set in the 12th Five Year Plan, as opposed to lying about
production figures, they would have been prevented by bureaucrats whose only
concern was to meet their own targets via their dependence on outdated methods.
Reform could not be sustained without greater restructuring, including
decentralisation. By the time acceleration was dropped in 1988, attempt at
economic reform had failed.
After acceleration, phase two
perestroika followed which was titled “Radical Reform from Above”, which at
first suggests that Gorbachev intended to reform the economy to a greater
extent after him and Party reformers realised tinkering simply wasn’t enough.
The reforms attempted during this phase intended to give enterprise managers
more accountability. The Law on State Enterprises in January 1988 meant
managers would be elected by workers, and had more responsibility in finances
and decision-making. But in actuality, the ministries still had final control,
maintaining the centrally-planned economic model. This was the same case in the
Law on Cooperatives in May 1988, which legalised private enterprise, suggesting
that unlike with the Law on Individual Labour Activity during acceleration,
Gorbachev now had more conviction to bring about successful reform that went
beyond tinkering. However, because he would not remove the central planning
system, enterprises outside of that were starved of resources and forced to
barter with other enterprises, making them slow to develop. This became another
example of what Laver calls Gorbachev’s “hotchpotch of initiatives”. The
presence of central planning, despite causing reform to fail, and reducing
national income to -4% by 1990, would not be removed by Gorbachev, and this is
explicitly emphasised in his rejection of the Shatalin Plan, which proposed to
move the economy to a market-based system within 500 days. It was rejected for
its proposed decentralisation of economic powers to the Republics. Therefore,
even as the economy was verging on collapse, the traditional framework of
central-planning continued, showing a lack of reform from economic perestroika.
As Popolov notes, perestroika “was done with slogans, and not a programme of
reform”, it lacked substance and the actual conviction to bring about effective
reform, rather tried to satisfy both political sides of the spectrum, leading
it to become nothing more than “slogans” that failed to materialise into economic
success.
The fact that “bureaucratic
obstructionism” was what caused economic reform to fail already suggests that
his political perestroika also failed to reform the political system of the
USSR. He hoped to democratise the USSR by introducing the publicly-elected
Congress of People’s Deputies, who would then elect members of the Supreme
Soviet. This “two-tier” structure was then adopted at all-Union level. It
attempted to transform the political landscape from a One-Party System to a
democratised state, and while the introduction of a publicly-elected body was
progress, in reality this progress was very limited. 750 out of 2500 seats were
reserved for public organisations, 100 of these seats being reserved for the
Party, already showing that the extent of democracy, thereby the extent of
reform, was limited. Furthermore, when the actual elections took place in March
1989, almost 90% of the elected deputies were Party members, due to elections
being rigged, showing how democratisation failed to materialise as corruption
and bureaucracy continued at a local level that Gorbachev failed to effectively
combat. This failure to combat bureaucracy and corruption, as well as
continuing the control of the conservative ministers in the Party demonstrates
how while on the surface it appeared both economic and political systems were
being reshaped, this only masked the continuation of Stalinist deficiencies
that was causing stagnation, which were all dependent on the centralisation to
the Party that existed economically, although this was reduced to a greater
extent politically.
The formation of opposition
parties may indicate that the political system had been successfully reformed,
including the Bloc of Democratic Russia which called for the removal of the
Communist Party and free elections. Furthermore, power for the Party was no
longer guaranteed, and such organisations did defeat some Party candidates for
Congress, showing how the power of the Party had been reduced. But this is
undermined when considering that the Party still had control of the KGB and the
military, emphasising a lack of decline in their control. Therefore, while
there was certainly more reform being made on a political level as opposed to
economic through perestroika, there was not total reform as the limits to
democratisation were made clear by the continued prominence of the Party. And
because the bureaucrats of the Party maintained their control, but at the same
time feared it being taken away from them, this made them determined to also
maintain economic control as they continued to obstruct attempts of economic
reform, leading to its failure.
Alongside perestroika,
Gorbachev’s policy of glasnost was introduced in 1986, but it must immediately
be acknowledged that glasnost never intended to advocate complete freedom,
especially in the media, already limiting the extent to which it could have
reformed the political system. Rather, Gorbachev wanted greater openness to
strengthen perestroika. When media freedom was allowed, presided over by
Yakolev, Gorbachev actually thought there was too much, but reform even then
was limited because publishers monitored output. Furthermore, Glasnost got off
to a bad start with the Chernobyl disaster, Gorbachev only spoke publicly about
it 2 weeks after the disaster occurred, and it received limited press coverage
within the USSR, with facts surrounding the event being misconstrued. This
shows a continuation of political control over the media, therefore the extent
of reform glasnost achieved has to be viewed as limited. However, as Laver
notes, Glasnost proved to be “a double-edged sword”; it must also be
acknowledged that because of glasnost, topics that were previously viewed as
taboo could be discussed in public, including suicide and abortion, and texts
that were banned for their criticism of the system like Doctor Zhivago were
published in the USSR for the first time. However, there remained the political
desire among conservatives to control society, as there was now less respect
for the Party and public discontent once perestroika was failing to materialise
economic benefit, and this combined with the decline of political power via
attempted democratisation meant conservatives called for the 1990 Law on Press Freedom,
making it illegal to abuse freedom of speech by spreading information that
didn’t correspond to reality, and thus undermining the reform glasnost had
achieved prior.
Therefore, while glasnost and
political perestroika meant openness and democratisation were taking place in
the political system of the USSR, their impact was limited because of the
continued desire for control of conservative bureaucrats, who also stifled
reform on an economic scale. But the fault for the lack of reform does not simple
lie with external factors, perestroika in itself was an incoherent and inconsistent
policy calling for a “halfway house” combining two conflicting systems of
central planning and market forces. So long as central planning existed, reform
could not truly materialise to the extent it needed to.